|
![]() |
Foreign
Headaches by Michael Greve and Richard Epstein In two important
cases decided in June, the U.S. Supreme Court has addressed some of
the tricky jurisdictional dimensions in international antitrust
disputes. The good news is that the high court has overcome its
studied indifference to these vital issues. The bad news is that only
one of the justices�Stephen Breyer�has taken a sensible and
coherent view of the matter. F.
Hoffman-LaRoche v. Empagran
construed the Foreign Trade Antitrust Improvements Act of 1982.
Enacted during a fit of industrial-policy enthusiasm and anti-Japanese
hysteria, it legalizes U.S. export cartels�that is, price agreements
and output restrictions that would earn their practitioners prison
time if targeted at American consumers. The act, however, denies this
cartel exemption to conspiracies that have a �direct, substantial,
and reasonably foreseeable effect� on U.S. consumers. Empagran asked
whether foreign entities could sue in U.S. courts for harms suffered
abroad, so long as the defendants had also similarly harmed Americans
through a worldwide scheme. Writing
for a unanimous court, Breyer answered that question�which had split
the circuits�in the negative. Opening the U.S. courts to these sorts
of disputes, he reasoned, would turn them into havens for litigating
other countries� problems. U.S. courts might unwisely provide a
forum for litigants who would otherwise come up empty-handed at home.
Enterprising American judges could exacerbate international tensions
by condemning practices that foreign countries have decided to
tolerate, or even promote. Breyer pointed to amicus briefs by Canada,
Japan and Germany, which insisted that their efforts to combat
international cartels�by offering leniency to corporate turncoats
who report hard-to-detect cartel arrangements�would be compromised
if the volunteers were to face prosecution in the United States. While
antitrust lawyers will long argue over the technical aspects of
Empagran, its basic message is clear: Let foreign countries take care
of their antitrust problems, and we shall take care of ours, each
nation responding to global cartels as it sees fit. Alas,
it took the justices only one week to muddy that plain, salutary
message. In Intel Corp. v. Advanced Micro Devices [AMD], the
court construed a federal comity provision that allows U.S. courts to
order, at the request of �any interested party,� the production of
documents �for use in a foreign or international tribunal.� Here,
the �tribunal� was the European Commission, before whom AMD had
filed a complaint alleging that Intel had committed various antitrust
violations, including loyalty discounts and price discrimination. Most
likely, AMD�a U.S. company�chose a European forum to proceed
against another U.S. company because the European law on the abuse of
a dominant-market position is more favorable to complainants than the
analogous prohibition in the Sherman Act. AMD then turned to American
courts to compel the disclosure of documents that would be
discoverable neither here nor in Europe. It
takes willful blindness to ignore the enormous potential for abuse and
international friction. The European Commission insists that it does
not constitute a tribunal at all but is rather Courting trouble
But
as Breyer observed in his Intel dissent, why invite
international friction by helping foreign authorities over their own
objections? We should adopt a per se rule against discovery requests
that exceed the parties� procedural rights under foreign law and, in
analogous circumstances, under U.S. law. This tracked the principle of
Empagran: Just as U.S. courts should refrain from needlessly
adjudicating the world�s antitrust disputes, so the commission
should not become a haven for international litigants, taking
advantage of broad U.S. discovery rules only to later litigate in
Brussels. Sadly,
the fact that no other justice joined Breyer�s Intel dissent�even
while agreeing with his analogous reasoning in Empagran�suggests
that Empagran�s promise of comity and compartmentalization may prove
nearly empty. The bar to U.S. jurisdiction applies only when the
foreign injury is �independent��that is, unconnected to any
damage here. Since the effects of multinational transactions cannot
easily be broken into domestic and foreign components, lower courts
may follow Empagran�s logic only in a narrow set of cases. This could be most unfortunate. International mega-mergers and other global transactions will often present vexing jurisdictional and diplomatic conflicts. Many hard cases lack a clean jurisdictional solution. That is all the more reason to compartmentalize antitrust enforcement along national lines whenever possible. |