Meet
Eliot Spitzer
The most destructive politician in
America.
This piece is the cover story in the June 14, 2004, issue of National
Review.
There's a story Eliot Spitzer likes to tell about the
Federalist Society. Spitzer had started to make a name for himself
as an aggressive and activist attorney general for New York, and
the conservative legal group invited him to speak. Spitzer told
the group that he too was a federalist: Conservatives had cut the
federal government down to size; that devolution of power, he
said, had freed him to sue the tobacco companies. The
conservatives, he says, were "ashen." Sometimes he adds
that he was not received graciously.
Spitzer's story does not hold up in all particulars. Leonard Leo,
the executive vice president of the Federalist Society, says,
"He was not greeted stonily. He has a wildly different
recollection of his one appearance than anyone else who was in
attendance." Leo says the society has invited him back.
The underlying point of Spitzer's story, however, is true. A
generation of conservative rhetoric about federalism and states'
rights has made the political culture receptive to state-level
activism. And nobody better embodies the new legal activism of the
state attorneys general than Eliot Spitzer. Nor does anyone better
illustrate the damage that activism is doing to our form of
government. If conservatives are going to resist that activism, as
they should, they will have to rethink some of their slogans.
Spitzer now cuts a large figure. He is feared on Wall Street,
loved by the press, and considered a strong candidate for governor
in 2006. But he almost didn't make it into public office. After
Princeton, Harvard Law, and a brief stint at a law firm, Spitzer
went to work fighting the mob for the Manhattan district
attorney's office. In 1994, he ran for attorney general - and
placed fourth out of four in the Democratic primary. In 1998, he
spent even more of his father's real-estate millions to unseat the
incumbent Republican. This time, he won - barely. The recount went
on for six weeks.
The photo finish did not make him cautious as AG. The list of
targets Spitzer has gone after seems endless: gun makers, tobacco
companies, Internet spammers, drug companies, Microsoft,
brokerages, predatory lenders, mutual funds, power plants, the
Bush administration, former New York Stock Exchange chairman
Richard Grasso. Spitzer's activism has earned him an exceedingly
good press. He is most famous for going after Wall Street brokers
who sought to woo corporate investment-banking clients by touting
their lousy stocks to investors. After that episode, Time magazine
named him "Crusader of the Year" and compared him to
Moses.
Spitzer's critics - he does have them - allow that he is smart and
hardworking. But they fault him for being an ambitious publicity
hound. He replies that he's happy to have people impugn his
motives when they can't challenge the merits of his actions. It is
a fair retort: In a healthy political system, public officials
will often do the right thing for the wrong reason. If pursuit of
the governor's mansion has led Spitzer to advance the common good,
we should be glad of it.
The crucial question, then, is whether Spitzer's activism has
advanced the common good. There is room for doubt.
Guns. Lawsuits against gun manufacturers have been one of
Spitzer's major causes. In 1999 and 2000, he worked hard to get
Smith & Wesson to agree to adopt trigger locks, develop
"smart gun" technology, change the marketing of its
product, and support gun-control legislation. At the last minute,
Andrew Cuomo, then Clinton's secretary of Housing and Urban
Development and a man who wanted to be governor of New York
himself, took over the negotiating, snatching credit away from
Spitzer. But what both men were doing was using the threat of
litigation to get the company to agree to government regulations
that Congress and state legislators were unwilling to enact.
Moreover, they were trying to exploit Smith & Wesson's market
power to get other companies to follow suit. According to the
settlement, Smith & Wesson would be able to sell only through
dealers who accepted a variety of restrictions. As Walter Olson, a
critic of the arrangement, put it, "If dealers and gun shows
wanted to stock the dominant manufacturer's line, they'd have to
agree to stop promoting disfavored, competitive product
lines."
It didn't work. Dealers started dropping Smith & Wesson, and
other gun companies pulled out of a joint legal defense with it.
Spitzer's response was to threaten lawsuits against the
non-cooperating companies.
Spitzer and Cuomo also made another run at gun makers. Working
with big-city mayors, Spitzer sued the firearm manufacturers on
the theory that guns are a "nuisance," just like
drifting smoke or stray dogs, that keeps people from enjoying
their homes. The case was thrown out of court. Spitzer appealed,
and it was thrown out again. The appeals court ruled that "[s]uch
lawsuits could be leveled not merely against these defendants, but
well beyond them, against countless other types of commercial
enterprises, in order to address a myriad of societal problems -
real, perceived or imagined - regardless of the distance between
the causes of the problems and their alleged consequences, and
without any deference to proximate cause." Also: "Courts
are the least suited, least equipped, and thus the least
appropriate branch of government to regulate and micro-manage the
manufacturing, marketing, distribution and sale of handguns."
Tobacco. Spitzer was a latecomer to the states' litigation against
the tobacco companies, which began before his tenure. He has since
become a key player in defending the settlement of that
litigation.
The states alleged that the tobacco companies owed them because
smoking increased their Medicaid costs. The suits were proceeding
successfully through the courts - in some states, because the
legislature changed the law so that the tobacconists could not use
the same defenses available to other companies. The attorneys
general, the tobacco companies, and the trial lawyers reached an
agreement. It was submitted to Congress for approval, but
opponents blocked that approval. So the leading attorneys general
reached a very similar agreement with the companies and the
lawyers, this time cutting Congress out.
Under this deal, the companies have to pay the states billions of
dollars. They could raise the money by hiking prices - and without
worrying about losing market share. Under the terms of the
agreement, a company's payments would rise if its market share
did. So nobody had an incentive to keep prices low. Small
companies that weren't part of the deal were invited to join it at
favorable payment rates, in return for not trying to grow larger.
The states took additional steps to make sure that any new
companies entering the market would also enter the agreement.
The results: a de facto national tax on cigarettes that Congress
never passed, and a tobacco-industry cartel protected by the
states. The state attorneys general are now quite prepared to help
quash private lawsuits against the tobacco companies that might
threaten the flow of cash to state governments.
"Predatory mortgage lending." Until the Treasury
Department told him to back off, Spitzer was contemplating action
against subprime mortgage lenders, whose predation has
"become a new scourge" (to quote an article he co-wrote
in The New Republic). In the 1990s, the financial markets started
selling mortgages to people who don't qualify for prime mortgages
and thus have to pay more. The interest rates and fees for these
products are higher than Spitzer would like. In Spitzer's view,
most of the people who buy them "would be better off with no
loan at all." But if predation is taking place, subprime
lenders should have abnormally high profits. They don't. It is a
competitive market, and its peculiarities are not insidious: There
are high prepayment charges because a lot of people prepay. The
fee structure is complex and high because regulation effectively
keeps interest rates from rising to their market level. Spitzer
complains that subprime lending is racially discriminatory.
Whether that's correct depends on whether minority borrowers are
more capable of judging their own interests than he is.
Brokerages. This was the issue that made Spitzer a national name,
and he deserves credit for his work on it. He got his hands on
e-mails from Henry Blodget, Merrill Lynch's high-flying
Internet-stock analyst, in which Blodget confessed that he thought
the stocks he was touting were junk. He was selling them because
Merrill wanted the companies to which those stocks belonged as
investment-banking clients.
New York's Martin Act gave Spitzer sweeping powers to prosecute
securities fraud. As Nicholas Thompson summarized some of that
act's distinctive features in a recent article in Legal Affairs:
"People called in for questioning during Martin Act
investigations do not have a right to counsel or a right against
self-incrimination. Combined, the act's powers exceed those given
any regulator in any other state. . . . To win a case, the AG
doesn't have to prove that the defendant intended to defraud
anyone, that a transaction took place, or that anyone actually was
defrauded."
The Martin Act (1921) had not been used against Wall Street for a
long time. But Spitzer had occasion to learn about its existence:
During his 1998 race, his opponent accused him of financing his
campaign in a way that violated the act - a charge for which the
evidence was suggestive but not definitive. Once in office,
Spitzer started to use the act aggressively.
Merrill Lynch settled. Soon afterward, Spitzer started actions
against several other Wall Street companies and got them to
settle, too. The settlements included fines, which critics said
were too light. No matter: Spitzer was more interested in
restructuring the industry to reduce conflicts of interest.
Perhaps the government was right to crack down on these abuses.
Perhaps the regulations he devised are worthwhile, although there
are plausible criticisms. But state attorneys general are not
supposed to be in the business of issuing securities regulations.
Spitzer justifies his activism by pointing to the inaction of the
federal Securities and Exchange Commission. (The SEC has nothing
like the Martin Act, and is also constrained by federal
rule-making procedures.)
And what about the responsibilities of investors? Shouldn't they
have known to take investment advice with a grain of salt? "I
don't want to say the public shares responsibility," Spitzer
told Money. The Merrill Lynch case grew out of a private suit
brought by a man who lost half a million dollars through
recommended investments. If you've got half a million to lose, you
might want to consider buying some financial sophistication.
Merrill Lynch customers who have followed Spitzer's suits with
their own have lost their cases. One federal judge concluded:
"The facts and circumstances show beyond doubt that the
plaintiffs brought their own losses upon themselves when they
knowingly spun an extremely high-stakes wheel of fortune." It
may be that Merrill Lynch was undone not by the legal merits, but
by the threat that Spitzer would pummel its reputation by using
his Martin Act powers.
The "mutual-fund scandal." Spitzer next went after
mutual funds. Supposedly, they had cost investors $4.9 billion a
year by allowing a few people to engage in "late
trading" and "market timing." But according to
Henry Manne, the former dean of the George Mason University law
school, the damage to investors was much less, and the benefits
they received greater, than Spitzer claimed.
Late traders and timers exploit the 4 p.m. market closing time: If
new information comes out after that time, trading at the
"stale" closing price can be profitable. The $4.9
billion figure came from estimating the maximum amount that
short-term traders could make from these practices and then
assuming that all of their gains were made at the expense of
long-term investors.
The mutual-fund industry is, however, highly competitive, with
hundreds of companies and thousands of funds. If long-term
investors were getting lower returns from some funds because the
funds allowed timing, the investors could easily have gone
elsewhere.
Some of the funds' activity was clearly illegal. But serious harms
to investors have not been demonstrated. Moreover, the settlement
Spitzer imposed - lower fees - has no relation to the charges.
Stephen Bainbridge, a securities-law professor at UCLA, wrote,
"It's as though you got busted for pot possession and the DA
said you had to give up snowboarding." Spitzer isn't supposed
to be setting fees for the mutual-fund industry, however popular
that may be to New York voters.
GOVERNMENT BY LAWSUIT
Spitzer argues that his lawsuits and enforcement actions make
markets more efficient and fair. He isn't hostile to free markets;
he just recognizes that they require strong government. Moreover,
he claims that he is making government work better: He takes
action only when legislators have failed to. But it is unlikely
that establishing cartels or suppressing voluntary transactions
really strengthens markets. There is a deeper problem with
Spitzer's style of regulation through litigation: When legislators
"fail" to regulate guns, they may be choosing inaction
over the alternatives. When Spitzer tries to override that
decision, he exalts his own policy preferences above democratic
procedures.
And what is the attorney general of New York doing setting
national policy on guns, securities regulation, pollution, or any
other issue? During one phase of his Wall Street campaign, the
editors of the Wall Street Journal asked whether Spitzer was
running for governor of New Jersey - the worry being that
investment houses might decamp. The Journal has made many
warranted criticisms of Spitzer, but this one was off the mark: It
understated his ambitions. Spitzer does not claim jurisdiction
over Wall Street because it is located in his state; he claims
jurisdiction because some of its clients are. If firms moved to
New Jersey, or New Mexico, they would find that Spitzer and the
Martin Act had followed them there.
We are used to thinking of the "litigation explosion" or
"liability crisis" as an economic problem. It has an
overlooked political dimension: It is a breakdown of federalism.
Under the current dispensation, an Alabama plaintiff can sue an
Ohio company in an Alabama court, before an Alabama judge and
jury, so long as the company has at least "minimum
contacts" with Alabama. The court can decide to apply Alabama
law, because the Alabama government has an "interest":
It's the forum state. If Alabama's laws are better for plaintiffs
than Ohio's, over time Ohio will find its liability rules becoming
irrelevant. Alabama will be able, effectively, to create national
rules for product liability. That's the dynamic that brought the
liability crisis into being.
Michael Greve, the director of the American Enterprise Institute's
Federalism Project, argues that the activism of the attorneys
general represents a new, more virulent strain of the tort crisis.
Now the trial lawyers have badges. They want liberal social
policy, not just cash awards. The old tort shakedowns often
featured exaggerated or even non-existent harms. Lester Brickman,
in Pepperdine Law Review, argues that the asbestos litigation was
based on fraudulent claims. The new lawsuits hardly even bother to
demonstrate harms: An arcane theory of what the world would look
like if the target industry followed different marketing practice,
or adopted a different pricing structure, suffices.
Greve calls the emerging system of state-government power
"neo-Confederate," in contrast to the federalism found
in the Constitution. He's got a point. The fact that the Articles
of Confederation effectively allowed states to commit economic
aggression against one another was a major reason the Constitution
was adopted.
That doesn't mean the system will now degenerate into a war of all
against all. The states can find an equilibrium point of
collusion. Spitzer himself is mindful of the threat of regulatory
balkanization, which corporate America detests. The attorneys
general will make sure that we have uniform national policies -
they just won't be set in Washington.
The tobacco settlement offers a model for this future. How did the
states, including the tobacco-producing ones, come to a unanimous
agreement? Simple: Once a critical mass of states had reached a
deal with the companies, the other states were left with two
options. They could take the companies' payments or refuse them.
Either way, their smokers were paying the higher fees. Even
Alabama's Bill Pryor, the attorney general most opposed to the
deal, eventually signed on. The new activism of the attorneys
general may be one reason the position is now dominated by
Democrats. It certainly accounts for why Republican AGs act the
same way as the Democrats.
Federalism properly conceived would leave room for regulatory
activism, but that activism would be constrained because state
laws would have little extraterritorial reach. Washington should
probably back off on subprime mortgage lending: Let Spitzer take
whatever action he wishes. So long as the costs of regulation are
borne inside the state, there is a limit to how far it will go.
Georgia passed a draconian law on subprime lending, saw its market
collapse, and had to repeal the statute.
Delaware is the corporate-chartering capital of the country
because corporations get to choose which state's legal regime to
adopt. If securities regulation were handled under the same
choice-of-law principle that governs corporate law, Spitzer's
reign would not be troubling. As Greve puts it, brokerage houses
"could accede to Spitzer's regime and wear his oversight as a
badge of honor and integrity or else migrate to a more hospitable
jurisdiction." Spitzer would then "function as credible
intermediary agent in a market where private, self-regulatory
institutions, as well as federal regulators, seem to have failed.
Not as exalted a role as that of Global Investors' Avenger - but a
vastly more valuable and appropriate one."
A VACUUM OF POWER
Spitzer often says that he is acting because the federal
government has not. He is right, in a sense. The state attorneys
general can exercise the powers they do only because neither
Congress nor the federal courts have imposed constraints on them.
It is hard, however, to see who is going to stop the AGs.
It won't be the business lobby. A lot of companies are afraid to
take on Spitzerian activists for fear they will be the target of
the next enforcement action. Besides, life on the inside of
cartelizing deals is rather cozy. Spitzer is not some left-winger
out to bankrupt industries. Indeed, he can offer protection from
other attorneys general and from private litigants who might be so
inclined. Don't be surprised if, in a few years' time, America's
pharmaceutical industry decides to become a regulated public
utility in everything but name, with a lot less innovation but a
guaranteed rate of return. If it happens, the deal will be made
with the attorneys general, not Congress.
The U.S. Constitution is an obstacle to the AGs - or would be, if
anyone remembered what it was. The Constitution does not contain
any provisions that mention "federalism." It does,
however, include provisions that limit the reach of the federal
government over states, and provisions that limit the states'
ability to plunder one another's citizens. The compact clause, for
example, requires a congressional majority to authorize agreements
among the states. Dairy-producing states can't just form a cartel
to mulct all the other states; they can do that only when Congress
says it is okay (as it does). Under the clause, the tobacco deal
should have been required to get congressional approval. The
full-faith-and-credit clause requires that state courts show some
deference to sister states' laws - a rule that would bring the
tort crisis under control by restraining forum shopping.
But while the Supreme Court has seen a modest revival of
federalist limits on the national government in recent decades,
limits on state governments' ability to set national policies
remain dead. The liberal justices are voting for regulation by
litigation, and the conservatives are voting for "states'
rights" - at the risk, Greve notes, of transforming the
Constitution into a "trial lawyers' bill of rights."
Conservatives, too, seem inclined to bless anything the states
want to do as "federalism." In various debates over the
last decade, many Republicans have acted as though unlimited
discretion on the part of state governments in spending federal
money was part of the Founders' design. In the name of taxing
Internet sales, most of the nation's governors are trying to
create a tax-collection system that will ensure that when a family
from Maine goes on vacation in Florida, it will bring Maine's
taxes with it. People seem at least to understand that a state
sales-tax cartel requires congressional approval. But too many
self-described conservatives are leading the charge for that
approval (as are important companies such as Wal-Mart). We now
have a "federalism" that subverts the goals of citizen
choice and political accountability that it was meant to serve.
Eliot Spitzer may never become governor. He is said to be
concerned that Sen. Charles Schumer is better positioned for the
2006 primaries. Given the trend lines, however, he may want to
consider whether the job would be a demotion.
|